Transportation and Economic Development
Authors: Dr. Jean-Paul Rodrigue and Dr. Theo Notteboom
1. The Economic Importance of Transportation
Development is related at improving the welfare of a
society through appropriate social, political and
economic conditions. The expected outcomes are
quantitative and qualitative improvements in human
capital (e.g. income and education levels) as well as
physical capital such infrastructures (utilities,
transport, telecommunications).
While in the previous decades, development policies and
strategies tended to focus on physical capital, recent
years has seen a better balance by including human
capital issues. Irrespective of the relative importance
of physical versus human capital, development cannot
occur without both as infrastructures cannot remain
effective without proper operations and maintenance
while economic activities cannot take place without an
infrastructure base.Because of its intensive use of
infrastructures,
the transport sector is an important component of the economy
and a common tool used for development. This is even
more so in a global economy where economic opportunities
have been increasingly related to the mobility of people,
goods and information. A relation between the quantity and quality
of transport infrastructure and the level of economic development
is apparent. High density transport infrastructure and
highly connected networks are commonly associated with
high levels of development. When transport systems are efficient, they
provide economic and social opportunities and benefits
that result in positive multipliers effects such as better
accessibility to markets, employment and additional investments.
When transport systems are deficient in terms of capacity
or reliability, they can have an economic cost such as
reduced or missed opportunities and lower quality
of life.At the aggregate level, efficient transportation
reduces costs in many economic sectors, while inefficient
transportation increases these costs. In addition, the impacts
of transportation are not always intended and can have unforeseen
or unintended consequences. For instance, congestion is
often an unintended consequence in the provision of free
or low cost transport infrastructure to the users.
However, congestion is also the indication of a
growing economy where capacity and infrastructure
have difficulties keeping up with the rising
mobility demands. Transport
carries an important social and environmental load,
which cannot be neglected. Assessing the economic importance
of transportation requires a
categorization
of the types of impacts it conveys. These involve core
(the physical characteristics of transportation),
operational and geographical dimensions:
Core. The most fundamental impacts of transportation
relate to the physical capacity to convey passengers
and goods and the associated costs to support this mobility.
This involves the setting of routes enabling new or
existing interactions between economic entities.
Operational. Improvement in the
time performance, notably in terms of reliability, as
well as reduced loss or damage. This implies a better
utilization level of existing transportation assets
benefiting its users as passengers and freight are conveyed
more rapidly and with less delays.
Geographical. Access to a wider
market base where economies of scale in production,
distribution and consumption can be improved.
Increases in productivity from the access to a larger
and more diverse base of inputs (raw materials, parts,
energy or labor) and broader markets for diverse outputs
(intermediate and finished goods). Another important
geographical impacts concerns the influence of transport
on the location of activities.
The economic importance
of the transportation industry can thus be assessed
from a macroeconomic and microeconomic perspective:
At the macroeconomic level (the importance
of transportation for a whole economy), transportation
and the mobility it confers are linked to a level of
output, employment
and income within a national economy. In many developed
countries, transportation accounts between 6% and 12%
of the GDP.
At the microeconomic level (the
importance of transportation for specific parts of
the economy) transportation is linked to producer,
consumer and production costs. The importance of specific transport activities
and infrastructure can thus be assessed for each
sector of the economy.
Usually, higher income levels are associated with a
greater
share of transportation in consumption expenses. Transportation accounts on average between
10% and 15% of household
expenditures, while it accounts around 4% of the
costs of each unit of output in manufacturing, but this
figure varies greatly according to sub sectors.
The added value and employment effects of transport services
usually extend beyond those generated by
that activity; indirect effects are salient. For instance, transportation
companies purchase a part of their inputs (fuel, supplies, maintenance)
from local suppliers. The production of these inputs generates
additional value-added and employment in the local economy.
The suppliers in turn purchase goods and services from other
local firms. There are further rounds of local re-spending which
generate additional value-added and employment. Similarly, households
that receive income from employment in transport activities
spend some of their income on local goods and services. These
purchases result in additional local jobs and added value. Some
of the household income from these additional jobs is in turn
spent on local goods and services, thereby creating further
jobs and income for local households. As a result of these successive
rounds of re-spending in the framework of local purchases, the
overall impact on the economy exceeds the initial round of output,
income and employment generated by passenger and freight transport
activities. Thus, from a general standpoint the economic impacts
of transportation can be
direct, indirect and
induced:
Direct impacts. The outcome of improved capacity
and efficiency where transport provides employment, added
value, larger markets as well as time and costs improvements.
The overall demand of an economy is increasing.
Indirect impacts. The outcome of improved accessibility
and economies of scale. Indirect value-added and jobs are
the result of local purchases by companies directly dependent
upon transport activity. Transport activities are responsible
for a wide range of indirect value-added and employment
effects, through the linkages of transport with other economic
sectors (e.g. office supply firms, equipment and parts suppliers,
maintenance and repair services, insurance companies, consulting
and other business services).
Induced impacts. The outcome of the
economic multiplier effects where the price of commodities,
goods or services drops and/or their variety increases. For
instance, the steel industry requires cost efficient import
of iron ore and coal for the blast furnaces and export activities
for finished products such as steel booms and coils. Manufacturers
and retail outlets and distribution centers handling imported
containerized cargo rely on efficient transport and seaport
operations.
Transportation links together the factors of production
in a complex web of relationships between producers and
consumers. The outcome is commonly a more efficient division
of production by an exploitation of geographical comparative
advantages, as well as the means to develop economies of
scale and scope. The productivity of space, capital and
labor is thus enhanced with the efficiency of distribution
and personal mobility. Economic
growth is increasingly linked with transport developments,
namely infrastructures, but also with managerial expertise,
which is
crucial for logistics. Thus, although transportation is
an
infrastructure intensive activity, hard assets must be
supported by an array of soft assets, namely management
and information systems. Decisions have
to be made about how to use and operate transportation systems
in a manner that optimize benefits and minimize costs
and inconvenience.
2. Transportation and Economic Opportunities
Transportation developments that have taken place since
the beginning of the industrial revolution have been linked
to growing economic opportunities.
At each stage of human societal development, a particular
transport technology has been developed or adapted with
an array of impacts.
Five major waves of economic development
where a specific transport technology created new
economic, market and social opportunities can be
suggested:
Seaports. Linked with the early stages of European
expansion from the 16th to the 18th centuries, commonly
known as the age of exploration. They supported
the early development of international trade through colonial
empires, but were constrained by limited inland access.
Later in the industrial revolution, many ports became
important heavy industrial platforms With globalization
and containerization, seaports increased their
importance as a support to international trade and
global supply chains.
Rivers and canals. The first stage of the industrial
revolution in the late 18th and early 19th centuries was
linked with the development of canal systems in Western Europe
and North America, mainly to transport heavy goods. This
permitted the development of rudimentary and constrained
inland distribution systems.
Railways. The second stage of industrial revolution
in the 19th century was linked with the development
and implementation of rail systems enabling more flexible and high capacity inland transportation systems.
This opened up substantial economic and social
opportunities through the extraction of resources, the
settlement of regions and the growing mobility of
freight and passengers.
Roads. The 20th century saw the rapid development of
comprehensive road transportation systems, such as national highway
systems, and of automobile manufacturing as a major
economic sector. Individual transportation became widely
available to mid income social classes, particularly
after the Second World War. This was associated with
significant economic opportunities to service industrial
and commercial markets with reliable door-to-door
deliveries. The automobile also permitted new forms of
social opportunities, particularly with suburbanization.
Airways and information technologies. The
second half of the
20th century saw the development of global air and telecommunication
networks in conjunction with economic globalization. New organizational
and managerial forms became possible, especially in the rapidly
developing realm of logistics and supply chain management.
Although maritime transportation is the physical
lynchpin of globalization, air transportation and IT
support the accelerated mobility of passengers,
specialized cargoes and their associated information
flows.
No single transport mode has been solely
responsible for economic growth. Instead, modes have been
linked with the economic functions they support and the geography in which growth
was taking place. The
first trade
routes established a rudimentary system of distribution
and transactions that would eventually be expanded by long
distance
maritime shipping networks and the setting of the first
multinational corporations managing these flows. Major flows
of international migration that occurred since the 18th
century were linked with the expansion of international
and continental transport systems that radically shaped
emerging economies such as in North America and Australia.
Transport played a catalytic role in these migrations,
transforming the economic and social geography of many nations.
Transportation has been a tool of territorial control and
exploitation, particularly during the colonial era where
resource-based transport systems
supported the extraction of commodities in the developing
world and forwarded them to the industrializing nations
of the time. The goal to capture resource and market opportunities
was a strong impetus in the setting and structure of transport
networks. More recently, port development, particularly
container ports, has been of strategic interest as a tool
of integration to the global economy as the case of
China illustrates.
There is a direct relation between
foreign trade and container port volumes, so
container port development is commonly seen as a tool to
capture the opportunities brought by globalization.
Further, technological and commercial developments have
incited a greater reliance on the
oceans as an economic
and circulation space.
Due to demographic pressures and increasing urbanization,
developing economies are characterized by a mismatch between
limited supply and growing demand for transport infrastructure.
While some regions benefit from the development of transport
systems, others are often marginalized by a set of conditions
in which inadequate transportation plays a role. Transport
by itself is not a sufficient condition for development.
However, the lack of transport infrastructures can be seen
as a constraining factor on development. In developing economies,
the lack of transportation infrastructures and regulatory
impediments are jointly
impacting economic development by conferring higher
transport costs, but also delays rendering supply chain
management unreliable. A poor transport service level can
negatively affect the competitiveness of regions and corporations
and thus have a negative impact on the regional added value
and employment. In 2007, the World Bank published its first
ever report which ranked nations according to their logistics
performance based on the
Logistics Performance
Index. Investment
in transport infrastructures is thus seen as a tool of regional
development, particularly in developing countries.
Transport investments also tend to have
declining marginal returns. While initial
infrastructure investments tend to have a high return since
they provide an entirely new range of mobility options,
the more the system is developed the more likely additional
investment would result in lower returns. At some point,
the marginal returns can be close to zero or even negative,
implying a shift of transport investments from wealth producing
to wealth consuming. A common fallacy is assuming that additional
transport investments will have a similar multiplying effect
than the initial investments had, which can lead to capital
misallocation. The most common reasons for the declining
marginal returns of transport investments are:
High accumulation of existing infrastructure. In a context of high level of accessibility and transportation
networks that are already extensive, further investments
usually result in marginal improvements. This means
that the economic impacts of transport investments tend
to be significant when infrastructures were previously
lacking and tend to be marginal when an extensive
network is already present. Additional investments can
thus have limited impact outside convenience.
Economic changes. As economies
develop, their function tends to shift
from the primary (resource extraction) and secondary
(manufacturing) sectors towards advanced
manufacturing, distribution and services. These sectors
rely on different transport systems and capabilities. While an economy
depending on manufacturing will rely on road, rail and
port infrastructures, a service economy is more oriented
towards the efficiency of logistics and urban transportation.
In all cases transport infrastructure are important,
but their relative importance in supporting the economy
may shift.
Clustering. Due
to clustering and
agglomeration,
several locations develop advantages that cannot be
readily reversed through improvements in accessibility.
Transportation can be a factor of concentration and
dispersion depending on the
context. Less accessible regions thus do not necessarily
benefit from transport investments if they are embedded
in a system of unequal relations.
Therefore, each transport development project must be considered independently
and contextually.
Since transport infrastructures are capital intensive
fixed assets, they are particularly vulnerable to
misallocations and malinvestments.
The standard assumption is that transportation investments
tend to be more wealth producing as opposed
to wealth consuming investments such as
services. Still, several transportation investments can
be wealth consuming if they merely provide convenience,
such as parking and
sidewalks,
or service a market size well below any possible economic
return, with for instance projects labeled "bridges
to nowhere". In such a context, transport investment
projects can be counterproductive by draining
the resources of an economy instead creating wealth and
additional opportunities. Since many transport
infrastructures are provided through public funds, they
can be subject to the pressures of special interest
groups, which can result in poor economic returns. Efficient and sustainable transport
markets and systems play a key role in regional development
although the causality between transport and wealth
generation is not always clear.
3. Types of Transportation Impacts
The relationship between transportation and economic development
is difficult to formally establish and has been debated
for many years. In some circumstances transport investments
appear to be a catalyst for economic growth while in others,
economic growth puts pressures on existing transport infrastructures
and incite additional investments. In a number of
regions around the world, transport markets and related
transport infrastructure networks are seen as key
drivers in the promotion of a more balanced and
sustainable development, particularly by improving accessibility and
the opportunities of less developed regions or disadvantaged social
groups. At start there are different
impacts on the transport providers (transport companies)
and the transport users. There are several layers of activity
that transportation can
valorize,
from a suitable location that experiences the development
of its accessibility through infrastructure investment to
a better usage of existing transport assets through more
efficient management.
This is further nuanced by the
nature, scale and scope
of possible impacts:
Timing of the development. The impacts
of transportation can precede (lead), occur during
(concomitantly) or take place
after (lag) economic development. The lag, concomitant and lead
impacts make it difficult to separate the specific contributions
of transport to development. Each case appears to
be specific to a set of timing circumstances that are difficult
to replicate elsewhere.
Types of impacts. They vary considerably as the spectrum
ranges from the positive to the negative. Usually
transportation investments promote economic development
while in rarer cases they may hinder a region by
draining its resources in unproductive transportation
projects.
Cycles of economic development provide
a revealing conceptual perspective about how
transport systems
evolve in time and space as they include the timing and
the nature of the transport impact on economic development.
This perspective underlines that after a phase of introduction
and growth, a transport system will eventually reach a phase
of maturity through geographical and market saturation.
There is also the risk of overinvestment, particularly when economic growth
is credit driven, which can lead to significant
misallocations
of capital.
The outcome is a surplus capacity in infrastructures and
modes creating deflationary pressures that undermines profitability.
In periods of recession that commonly follow periods of
expansion, transportation activities may experiment a
setback, namely in
terms of lower demand and a scarcity of capital investment.
Transport, as a technology, typically follows a path of
experimentation, introduction, adoption and diffusion and,
finally, obsolescence, each of which has an impact on the
rate of economic development. The most significant benefits and productivity
gains are realized
in the early to mid diffusion phases while later phases are facing diminishing
returns. Containerization
is a relevant example of such a diffusion behavior as
its productivity benefits were mostly derived in the
1990s and 2000s when economic globalization was
accelerating. Many technologies
go through what can be called a "hype
phase" with unrealistic expectations about
their potential and benefits and many are eventually
abandoned as the technology proves ineffective at
addressing market or operational requirements, or is
simply too expensive for the benefits it conveys. Since
transportation is capital intensive, operators tend to
be cautious before committing to new technologies and
the significant sunk costs they require. In addition,
transport modes and infrastructures are depreciating assets
that constantly require maintenance and upgrades. At some
point, their useful lifespan
is exceeded and the vehicle must be retired or the infrastructure
rebuilt. Thus, the amortization of transport investments must consider the lifespan of the concerned mode or infrastructure.
4. Transportation as an Economic Factor
Contemporary trends have underlined that economic development
has become less dependent on relations with the environment
(resources) and more dependent on relations across space.
While resources remain the foundation of economic activities,
the commodification of the economy has been linked with
higher levels of material flows of all kinds. Concomitantly,
resources, capital and even labor have shown increasing
levels of mobility. This is particularly the case for multinational
firms that can benefit from
transport improvements in two significant markets:
Commodity market. Improvement in the efficiency
with which firms have access to raw materials and parts
as well as to their respective customers. Thus, transportation
expands opportunities to acquire and sell a variety of commodities
necessary for industrial and manufacturing systems.
Labor market. Improvement in the access to labor
and a reduction in access costs, mainly by improved commuting
(local scale) or the use of lower cost labor (global scale).
Transportation provides market accessibility by linking
producers and consumers so that transactions can take
place.
A common fallacy in assessing the importance and impact
of transportation on the economy is to focus only on transportation
costs, which tend to be relatively low; in the range of 5 to 10% of the
value of a good. Transportation is an economic factor of
production of goods and services, implying that
it is fundamental in their generation, even if it accounts for a small share of
input costs. This implies that irrespective of the cost,
an activity cannot take place without the transportation
factor. Thus, relatively small changes in transport
cost, capacity and performance can have substantial
impacts on dependent economic activities.An efficient transport system
with modern infrastructures favors many economic changes,
most of them positive. The major impacts of
transport on economic factors can be categorized as follows:
Geographic specialization.
Improvements in transportation and communication favor a
process of geographical specialization that increases productivity
and spatial interactions. An economic entity tends to produce
goods and services with the most appropriate combination
of capital, labor, and raw materials. A region will
thus tend to specialize in the production of goods and services
for which it has the greatest advantages (or the least disadvantages)
compared to other regions as long as appropriate transport
is available for trade. Through geographic specialization
supported by efficient transportation, economic productivity
is promoted. This process is known in economic theory as
comparative advantages.
Large scale production. An efficient transport
system offering cost, time and reliability advantages
enables
goods to be transported over longer distances. This facilitates
mass production through economies of scale because larger
markets can be accessed. The concept of
“just-in-time” in
supply chain management has further
expanded the productivity of production and distribution
with benefits such as lower inventory levels and better
responses to shifting market conditions. Thus, the more
efficient transportation becomes, the larger the markets
that can be serviced and the larger the scale of production.
This results in lower unit costs.
Increased competition. When transport is efficient,
the potential market for a given product (or service) increases,
and so does competition. A wider array of goods and services
becomes available to consumers through competition which
tends to reduce costs and promote quality and innovation.
Globalization has clearly been associated with a competitive
environment that spans the world and enables consumers
to have access to a wider range of goods and services.
Increased land value. Land which is adjacent
or serviced by good transport services generally has greater
value due to the utility it confers to many activities.
Consumers can have access to a wider range of services
and retail goods while residents can have better
accessibility to employment, services, and social
networks, all of which transcribes in higher land value.
In some cases, transportation activities can lower land
value, particularly for residential
activities. Land located near airports and highways, near
noise and pollution sources, will thus be impacted by corresponding
diminishing land value.
Transport also contributes to economic development through
job creation and its derived
economic activities. Accordingly, a large number of
direct (freighters, managers,
shippers) and indirect (insurance, finance, packaging, handling,
travel agencies, transit operators) employment are associated
with transport. Producers and consumers take economic decisions
on products, markets, costs, location, prices which are
themselves based on transport services, their availability,
costs and capacity.
Media Services
and their Associated Infrastructures
World Road and Rail Network
Economic Impacts of Transportation Infrastructure
Socioeconomic Benefits of Transportation
Relationship between GDP and Motorization, Selected Asian
Countries, 1960-1990
Share of Consumption by Sector and Income, Developing
Countries
Transport Spending as Share of GDP, Selected Countries 2005
Employment in Transportation Occupations, United StatesComposition
of the GDP, United States
Transport Costs by Industry Type, 1999
Cumulative Waves of Transport Development
Cumulative Modal Contribution to Economic Opportunities
The Silk Road and Arab Sea Routes
Dutch East India Company, Trade Network, 17th Century
Resource-Based
Transport Systems The
Ocean Economy
China's Special Economic Zones
Global Exports and Container Throughput
Logistics Costs and Average Transit Time of a 20 Foot Container,
Mombasa – Nairobi (Kenya)
Logistic Performance Index
World Bank Average Annual Lending by Mode
Wealth Consumption Investment in Transport Infrastructure:
Repaving a Sidewalk
Main Types of Economies in Production, Distribution and
Consumption
Impact of Transport Cost Reductions on Inequality
A Multi-Layer Perspective about Transport and Economic Development
Time Sequence and Nature of Impacts between Transport and
Economic Development
Cycles, Space and Transportation
Business Cycles and Misallocations
Stages in a Bubble Impact
of Recessions on Consumption and Freight Rates
Lifespan of Main Transport Assets Long Wave Cycles
of Innovation
Diffusion Cycle of Containerization
Technology “Hype” Cycle Factors
behind the Development of Transport Systems Transport
Impacts on Market Opportunities
Trade, Transportation and Geographic Specialization
Just-in-Time and its Logistic